The most influential models of economic growth are all about people. These models predict that with a shrinking population, economic growth and technological progress stop and humanity stagnates into extinction. Metascience proposals focus mostly on improving the design of scientific institutions. This is surely important, but in the face of rapidly declining population growth rates it is like making a dam more efficient when the river is running dry.
Why Are People So Important?
Physical capital is subject to diminishing returns and depreciation which inevitably bring its impact on economic growth to zero. People, on the other hand, have increasing returns. As groups of people get larger, they can cooperate and specialize making the group more productive than the sum of its parts. But most importantly: People can share ideas.
When one person has an idea that makes them productive, it can be near-costlessly copied to all the other people in the economy, multiplying its effect. These increasing returns make people the driving force behind economic models of growth. There are important temporary sources of growth, like increasing education, research intensity, and labor force participation, but these are all changes to the percentage of your population that is devoted to discovering ideas and growing the economy. This percentage can only grow to 100 so the long run rate of growth is always constrained by the population growth rate.
Empirical Evidence
There is evidence that population is the fundamental input into economic growth and technological progress outside of theoretical models. There is the striking co-movement of population and per capita GDP over the long term.
Note that this is GDP per person so the direct increase in production that comes from adding an extra worker to the economy is not counted here, only the increases which come from raising worker’s productivity are shown.
This correlation is strong within countries and also across them. Michael Kremer finds that regions with larger starting populations several thousand years ago had faster technological change and population growth for the rest of their history. In general, an extremely simple model of a feedback loop between population and GDP per capita fits several thousand years of observed data so well that a Roman economist working for Julius Caesar with enough data on ancient Egypt could have accurately predicted world GDP and population today.
Worryingly, population growth rates are plummeting all around the world.
The decline has been more severe in rich countries at the frontier of growth. Population growth is already negative in Italy and Japan. Economic growth has been completely stagnant in Japan and Italy for about as long as they have had negative population growth rates. Economic growth in the US has been buttressed by increasing education and research intensity, but Chad Jones estimates that the US’ long run rate of growth is ~80% lower than the 2% per year average over the past several decades due to slow population growth rates.
But despite all of the importance that population growth is given in the foundational models of growth and the empirics, it doesn’t feature strongly in proposals to speed economic growth from metascience and progress studies.
One explanation for this is that raising fertility is just not tractable, so it makes sense to focus on other interventions which can be pushed over the finish line even if they aren’t the highest impact. This claim depends a lot on the political support for fertility interventions which I’m not too familiar with, but the data on existing fertility interventions suggest that certain policies can have large effects.
In 2014, the French government switched their child care rebates from a universal system to a means-tested system with sharp cutoffs at certain income levels. This study finds that the cutoff reduced births by 40% among the high income families in France! (I didn’t have time to fully vet this study and it seems like a huge effect from a relatively small intervention but there is a large literature on fertility interventions with varied but qualitatively similar conclusions).
There is lots of overlap between metascience and immigration reform which is probably the easiest way to increase birth rates, at least in the US, and comes with lots of other great benefits. But birth rates are falling globally, and for all the benefits that come from bringing immigrants to high-income countries, it will probably decrease their counterfactual birthrates. Reallocating people across the world is the right thing to do but it probably quickens the global demographic transition.
Metascience should take this prediction from the models of economic growth seriously: shrinking populations end growth. Long run growth rates are bounded by the growth rate of population, so if we want a world with rapid economic growth for the next several centuries, this is the binding constraint.
The problem is that depopulation is a self-reinforcing cycle. Many "developed" countries have made unsustainable commitments to pension and healthcare systems that depended on tax revenue from a growing workforce and economy. As the age dependency ratio rises and expense of maintaining these systems balloons, the only choice is to 1) Cut the benefits or 2) Raise taxes on the young. The latter seems to be preferred.
But the latter "solution" only adds to the burden on the young and discourages more children, reinforcing the cycle. At Risk & Progress, I have repeatedly argued that depopulation is the single greatest threat to humanity this century. It threatens to dampen growth, dampen specialization of labor, as well as weaken innovation capacity.
There do not seem to be any good solutions as pro-fertility policies I have studied this far have only had minor effects (though I will be exploring some more in another essay). Ironically, this comes at a time where we are also getting close to AI. Perhaps, if AI is aligned and safe, AI could mitigate the effects of global stagnation.
Interesting essay.
I am not disagreeing with you, but I would say that it is less about absolute population, and more about the population living in cities. Rural areas rarely make major contributions to science or technological innovation. The people in rural areas are too spread out geographically, and they focus their labor on getting enough food to eat. City dwellers have the time to focus on solving other problems, and the geographical concentration to share ideas and learn from others.
This matters because for virtually all of human history, few people lived in cities. If present trends continue, we will keep getting more urbanized, which might counteract lower populations.